TYPE I | TYPE II |
---|---|
multi-task jurisdictions | task-specific jurisdictions |
mutually exclusive jurisdictions at any particular level | overlapping jurisdictions at all levels |
limited number of jurisdictions | unlimited number of jurisdictions |
jurisdictions organized in a limited number of levels | no limit to the number of jurisdictional levels |
jurisdictions are intended to be permanent | jurisdictions are intended to be flexible |
Year | Constitutional
federalism (0-4) |
Special territorial
autonomy (0-2) |
Role of regions in
central government (0-4) |
Regional elections
(0-2) |
Summary score (0-12) |
|
Austria | 1950 1970 1990 2000 |
4 4 4 4 |
0 0 0 0 |
2 2 2 2 |
2 2 2 2 |
8 8 8 8 |
Belgium | 1950 1970 1990 2000 |
1 1 3 4 |
0 0 1 1 |
0 0 2 2 |
2 2 1 2 |
3 3 7 9 |
Denmark | 1950 1970 1990 2000 |
0 0 0 0 |
1 1 1 1 |
0 0 0 0 |
0 0 0 0 |
1 1 1 1 |
Finland | 1950 1970 1990 2000 |
0 0 0 0 |
1 1 1 1 |
0 0 0 0 |
0 0 0 0 |
1 1 1 1 |
France | 1950 1970 1990 2000 |
0 1 2 2 |
0 0 0.5 0.5 |
0 0 0 0 |
0 0 2 2 |
0 1 4.5 4.5 |
Germany | 1950 1970 1990 2000 |
4 4 4 4 |
0 0 0 0 |
4 4 4 4 |
2 2 2 2 |
10 10 10 10 |
Greece | 1950 1970 1990 2000 |
0 0 0 1 |
0 0 0 0 |
0 0 0 0 |
0 0 0 0 |
0 0 0 1 |
Ireland | 1950 1970 1990 2000 |
0 0 0 0 |
0 0 0 0 |
0 0 0 0 |
0 0 0 0 |
0 0 0 0 |
Italy | 1950 1970 1990 2000 |
0 0 2 3 |
1 1 0 0 |
0 0 0 1 |
0 2 2 2 |
1 3 4 6 |
Netherlands | 1950 1970 1990 2000 |
1 1 1 1 |
0 0 0 0 |
0 0 0 0 |
2 2 2 2 |
3 3 3 3 |
Portugal | 1950 1970 1990 2000 |
0 0 1 1 |
0 0 1 1 |
0 0 0 0 |
0 0 0 0 |
0 0 2 2 |
Spain | 1950 1970 1990 2000 |
0 0 3 3 |
0 0 2 2 |
0 0 0 1 |
0 0 2 2 |
0 0 7 8 |
Sweden | 1950 1970 1990 2000 |
0 0 0 0 |
0 0 0 0 |
0 0 0 0 |
0 0 0 0 |
0 0 0 0 |
United Kingdom |
1950 1970 1990 2000 |
0 1 1 1 |
1 1 0 2 |
0 0 0 0 |
0 0 0 0 |
1 2 1 3 |
Table 2 measures regional governance along two dimensions: the extent to which a regional government exercises authority independently from central government, and the extent to which a regional government participates in national or European decision making. (1)
We apply Daniel Elazars notion that federalism combines self rule (autonomy) with shared rule (power sharing) (Elazar 1987). We evaluate self-rule by scoring constitutional federalism, special territorial autonomy and regional elections. We evaluate shared rule by scoring the role of regions in central government. For country-by-country details of coding decisions see Hooghe and Marks, 2001.
Constitutional federalism taps the formal scope of regional government within the state as a whole. We assign one point for each of the following characteristics:
These features are usually, but not always, cumulative. That is to say that the first characteristic is a requisite for the second, the second a requisite for the third, and the third a requisite for the fourth.
By special territorial autonomy we refer to the decentralization of authority to territorial minorities, not merely deconcentration of administration. Our scale varies from 0.5 to 2 and is derived by multiplying scores for the following criteria:
authoritative competencies:
0.5 = weak authoritative competencies;
1 = extensive authoritative competencies (same as entry for constitutional federalism)population coverage:
1 = special arrangements for home rule for less than ten percent of the population;
2 = special arrangements for home rule for more than ten percent of the population.
Footnote
(1) We define as regions as the most authoritative tier of intermediate government. Intermediate level governance is equivalent to NUTS 1 and NUTS 2 regions in the European Unions categorization (Nomenclature des Unités Territoriales Statistiques), which we reproduce here in Table 3. Regions in our analysis range from Valle dAosta with a population of 119,000 to the 17.9 million in the case of North Rhine-Westphaliaa range that is similar to that among states in the United States. The regional level in a country may shift over time if regional institutions are reformed. This is the case for Belgium, where the region replaced the province in the early 1980s as the dominant meso level of government.
We distinguish two kinds of power sharing. First, regions can share rule because they collectively constitute a national legislature, usually a second chamber composed of representatives of regional parliaments or regional executives. Second, regional governments may share executive power to the extent that regional ministers and civil servants regularly negotiate legislation or executive decisions with their counterparts in central government.
legislative power sharing:
1= a chamber in the national legislature composed of representatives of regional governments or parliaments without wide-ranging legislative veto power
2 = a chamber in the national legislature composed of representatives of regional governments or parliaments with wide-ranging veto power
executive power sharing:
1 = regular intergovernmental meetings between central state and regional executives without authority to reach binding decisions
2 = regular intergovernmental meetings between central state and regional executives with authority to reach binding decisions
1 = the regional assembly is indirectly elected
2 = the regional assembly is directly elected
NUTS 1 |
N |
NUTS 2 |
N |
NUTS 3 |
N |
|
Austria |
Gruppen von Bundesländern |
3 |
Bundesländer |
9 |
Gruppen von Politischen Bezirken |
35 |
Belgium |
Regios/ Régions |
3 |
Provincies/ Provinces |
10 |
Arrondissements |
43 |
Denmark |
|
1 |
|
1 |
Amter |
14 |
Finland |
Manner-Suomi/ Åland |
2 |
Suuralueet |
6 |
Maakunnat |
19 |
France |
ZEAT + DOM |
8+1 |
Régions + DOM |
22+4 |
Départements + DOM |
96+4 |
Germany |
Länder |
16 |
Regierungsbezirke |
40 |
Kreise |
543 |
Greece |
Groups of development regions |
4 |
Development regions |
13 |
Nomoi |
51 |
Ireland |
|
1 |
|
1 |
Regional authority regions |
8 |
Italy |
Gruppi di regioni |
11 |
Regioni |
20 |
Provincie |
103 |
Luxembourg |
|
1 |
|
1 |
|
1 |
Netherlands |
Landsdelen |
4 |
Provincies |
12 |
COROP-regios |
40 |
Portugal |
Continente+Regioes autonomas |
2 |
Commissaoes de coordenaçao regional + Regioes autonomas |
5+2 |
Grupos de Cancelhos |
30 |
Spain |
Agrupaciones de comunidades autonomas |
7 |
Comunidades autonomas + Ceuta y Melilla |
17+1 |
Provincias |
50 |
Sweden |
|
1 |
Riksområden |
8 |
Län |
24 |
United Kingdom |
Standard regions |
11 |
Groups of counties |
35 |
Counties/local authorities areas |
65 |
EU |
77 |
207 |
1030 |
Note: NUTS division as revised in 1995 by Eurostat. Source: Antonia Casellas & Catherine Galley (1999).
Issue arena |
1950 |
1957 |
1968 |
1992 |
2000 |
ECONOMIC POLICY |
|||||
Goods/services |
1 |
2 |
4 (3) |
4 |
4 |
Agriculture |
1 |
1 |
4 |
4 |
4 |
Capital flows (2) |
1 |
1 |
1 |
4 |
4 |
Persons/workers (3) |
1 |
1 |
2 |
3 |
4 |
Transportation |
1 |
2 |
2 |
2 |
3 (2) |
Energy (4) |
1 |
2 |
1 |
2 |
2 |
Communications |
1 |
1 |
1 |
2 |
3 (2) |
Environment (5) |
1 |
2 |
2 |
3 |
3 |
Regional development (6) |
1 |
1 |
1 |
3 |
3 |
Competition |
1 |
2 |
3 (2) |
3 |
3 |
Industry (7) |
1 |
2 |
2 |
2 |
3 (2) |
Money/credit |
1 |
1 |
2 |
2 |
4 (5) |
Foreign exchange/loans |
1 |
1 |
3 (2) |
2 |
4 |
Revenue/taxes |
1 |
1 |
3 (2) |
2 |
3 (2) |
Macroeconomic (8) |
1 |
1 |
2 |
2 |
4 (3) |
SOCIAL/INDUSTRIAL POLICY |
|||||
Work conditions |
1 |
1 |
2 |
2 |
3 |
Health |
1 |
1 |
1 |
2 |
2 |
Social welfare |
1 |
2 |
2 |
2 |
2 |
Education and research |
1 |
1 |
3 (2) |
2 |
3 (2) |
Labor-management relations |
1 |
1 |
1 |
1 |
3 (2) |
LEGAL-CONSTITUTIONAL POLICY |
|||||
Justice and property rights (9) |
1 |
1 |
1 |
3 |
4 (3) |
Citizenship (10) |
1 |
1 |
1 |
2 |
3 |
Participation |
1 |
1 |
2 (1) |
2 |
2 |
Police and public order (11) |
1 |
1 |
2 (1) |
1 |
2 |
INTERNATIONAL RELATIONS/EXTERNAL SECURITY |
|||||
Commercial negotiations |
1 |
1 |
3 |
5 |
5 |
Economic-military assistance |
1 |
1 |
1 |
2 |
4 (2) |
Diplomacy and membership of international organizations |
1 |
1 |
2 (1) |
2 |
4 (3) |
Defense & war |
1 |
1 |
1 |
2 |
3 (2) |
Key:
(1) Source for estimates, 1950-1968: Lindberg and Scheingold (1970: 67-71). Source for estimates, 1992-2000, Schmitter (1996b: 125-126). Estimates for 1992 and 2000 are based on projections from existing treaty obligations and obligations undertaken subsequently. Schmitter's scores were based on judgments provided by Geoffrey Garrett, Peter Lange, Gary Marks, Philippe C. Schmitter and David Soskice in March 1992. Scores in parentheses ( ) for 1968 represent ex post revaluations in March 1992 of the original scores in Lindberg & Scheingold by Garrett et al. Scores in parentheses ( ) for 2000 represent ex post revaluations in March 2000 of the original scores in Schmitter by Hooghe and Marks.
(2) Category not in Lindberg & Scheingold. Schmitter estimates for 1950-1968.
(3) Category not in Lindberg & Scheingold. Schmitter's estimates for 1950-1968.
(4) Category not in Lindberg & Scheingold. Schmitter's estimates for 1950-1968.
(5) Defined as Exploitation and protection of natural resources in Lindberg & Scheingold.
(6) Category not in Lindberg & Scheingold. Schmitter's estimates for 1950-1968.
(7) Called Economic development and planning in Lindberg & Scheingold.
(8) Called Counter-cyclical policy in Lindberg & Scheingold.
(9) Category not in Lindberg & Scheingold. Schmitter's estimates for 1950-1968.
(10) Category not in Lindberg & Scheingold. Schmitter's estimates for 1950-1968.
(11) Called Public health, safety and maintenance of public order in Lindberg & Scheingold.